In his recent article in Advisor Perspectives, fellow actuary Joe Tomlinson raises serious credibility concerns about Monte Carlo simulations that use historical data to calculate the expected equity premium for stocks when such simulations are used to determine how much wealth to spend down during retirement. Mr. Tomlinson points out that out limited statistical evidence regarding equity premiums produces levels of uncertainty that are unacceptable to most clients.
As I have indicated in prior posts (see for example my posts of July 15 of last year and January 24th and 25th of this year), I am not a buyer of the supposed superiority of Monte Carlo modeling as a tool for developing reasonable spending budgets for retirees. These Monte Carlo models are also frequently used to develop static withdrawal strategies (see my last post for discussion of the superiority of dynamic over static approaches). Mr. Tomlinson article confirms some of my major concerns about using Monte Carlo simulations and static approaches.
While the simple spreadsheets provided in this website can accommodate higher equity premium investment return assumptions, I recommend (at least for determining essential expense budgets) that retirees use an investment return assumption that is approximately equivalent to interest rates baked into single premium immediate life annuities at the time of determination. For example, an immediate monthly life annuity of $582 ( yesterday from Income Solutions.com) for a 65-year old male with a life expectancy of 274 months under the Society of Actuaries’ 2012 Individual Annuitant Mortality Table with 1% mortality projection translates into approximately a 4.5% annual interest rate. As I have previously indicated, including riskier assets in your portfolio (such as equities) can increase your expected rate of return, but it will also generally increase variability and therefore may not increase your annual spending budget over the long-run.
The Actuarial Approach is a dynamic approach that involves periodic (usually annually) remeasurement of the retiree’s assets and liabilities and possible periodic adjustments to the spending budget, not a one-and-done static approach developed using Monte Carlo modelling. I caution you to question the data used in Monte Carlo simulations producing a spending budget for you that significantly differs from the budget you (or your financial advisor) develop using the Actuarial Approach.
Budget Pun of the Day (My first and probably my last one): You’ll feel Stuck with your debt if you don’t properly Budge it.
Developing and maintaining a robust financial plan in retirement is a classic actuarial problem involving the time-value of money and life contingencies. This problem is easily solved with basic actuarial principles, including periodic comparisons of household assets and spending liabilities.
Wednesday, November 18, 2015
Tuesday, November 17, 2015
Retirement Researcher Quantifies Benefits of Dynamic Withdrawal Strategies
Thanks to Nelson Murphy for drawing my attention to an article in the Summer, 2015 edition of The Journal of Retirement Research, by David Blanchett, Head of Retirement Research for Morningstar Investment Management. The article is entitled, “Dynamic Choice and Optimal Annuitization.” This article is fairly technical, but I found the investment of time and energy required to wade through it to be generally worthwhile.
As a result of his analysis, Mr. Blanchett concludes that “there is a significant potential benefit to retirees who implement dynamic strategies.” He defines static strategies as those where the retiree makes decisions only at retirement (such as the 4% withdrawal rule or other types of safe withdrawal rule approaches) and dynamic strategies as those that involve intelligent changes during retirement (such as the approach advocated in this website). He also looked at dynamic vs. static annuitization strategies, but the differences in these two types of strategies was not as significant.
The dynamic withdrawal strategy used by Mr. Blanchett is approximately mathematically equivalent to the approach advocated in this website (assuming the retiree has no fixed dollar immediate or deferred annuities, no fixed dollar pension benefits and no specific bequest motive) and the same assumptions are used for investment return, inflation and mortality. If, instead of using the recommended assumptions in this website, you use Mr. Blanchett’s assumptions of 3% investment return, 2.5% inflation and life expectancy based on the Society of Actuaries 2012 Individual Annuity Mortality Table (without mortality improvement), you will develop roughly the same withdrawal rates shown in Exhibit 1 of Mr. Blanchett’s article.
Through his simulations, Mr. Blanchett also develops optimal levels of annuitization for retirees with different shortfall preferences, different bequest motives and different expected life expectancies. Of course the results of any analysis like this are dependent on the assumptions used and the assumed portfolio investment mix over the life of the retiree. The future economic assumptions employed by Mr. Blanchett include a 2.5% inflation rate, 3% bond yields, 9% per annum equity returns (with a standard deviation of 9.4%) and 50 basis point annual fee. The retiree is assumed to maintain a 40% equity/60% fixed income portfolio throughout retirement. While the optimal level of annuitization developed by Mr. Blanchett using these assumptions was lower with the dynamic withdrawal strategy than with the static withdrawal strategy, there were still some scenarios where annuitization was still optimal. Even though he assumed a 6.5% annual real rate of return on equities, on average annuitization was optimal for at least 25% of the retiree’s portfolio (in addition to Social Security) under these modeling assumptions as shown in his Exhibit 2.
Mr. Blanchett concludes that “implementing a dynamic withdrawal strategy alone (without annuities) resulted in higher levels of utility-adjusted wealth than a static withdrawal strategy that included both optimal immediate annuitization as well as dynamic annuitization.” He also concludes that delaying purchase of annuities for a while does not significantly affect outcomes for retirees compared with immediate purchase of annuities at retirement.
Bottom line: There were two things I liked about Mr. Blanchett’s research: 1) He favored a dynamic withdrawal approach very similar to the approach advocated in this website and 2) depending on their preferences and circumstances, retirees should consider investment of some percentage of their retirement portfolio in annuities.
As a result of his analysis, Mr. Blanchett concludes that “there is a significant potential benefit to retirees who implement dynamic strategies.” He defines static strategies as those where the retiree makes decisions only at retirement (such as the 4% withdrawal rule or other types of safe withdrawal rule approaches) and dynamic strategies as those that involve intelligent changes during retirement (such as the approach advocated in this website). He also looked at dynamic vs. static annuitization strategies, but the differences in these two types of strategies was not as significant.
The dynamic withdrawal strategy used by Mr. Blanchett is approximately mathematically equivalent to the approach advocated in this website (assuming the retiree has no fixed dollar immediate or deferred annuities, no fixed dollar pension benefits and no specific bequest motive) and the same assumptions are used for investment return, inflation and mortality. If, instead of using the recommended assumptions in this website, you use Mr. Blanchett’s assumptions of 3% investment return, 2.5% inflation and life expectancy based on the Society of Actuaries 2012 Individual Annuity Mortality Table (without mortality improvement), you will develop roughly the same withdrawal rates shown in Exhibit 1 of Mr. Blanchett’s article.
Through his simulations, Mr. Blanchett also develops optimal levels of annuitization for retirees with different shortfall preferences, different bequest motives and different expected life expectancies. Of course the results of any analysis like this are dependent on the assumptions used and the assumed portfolio investment mix over the life of the retiree. The future economic assumptions employed by Mr. Blanchett include a 2.5% inflation rate, 3% bond yields, 9% per annum equity returns (with a standard deviation of 9.4%) and 50 basis point annual fee. The retiree is assumed to maintain a 40% equity/60% fixed income portfolio throughout retirement. While the optimal level of annuitization developed by Mr. Blanchett using these assumptions was lower with the dynamic withdrawal strategy than with the static withdrawal strategy, there were still some scenarios where annuitization was still optimal. Even though he assumed a 6.5% annual real rate of return on equities, on average annuitization was optimal for at least 25% of the retiree’s portfolio (in addition to Social Security) under these modeling assumptions as shown in his Exhibit 2.
Mr. Blanchett concludes that “implementing a dynamic withdrawal strategy alone (without annuities) resulted in higher levels of utility-adjusted wealth than a static withdrawal strategy that included both optimal immediate annuitization as well as dynamic annuitization.” He also concludes that delaying purchase of annuities for a while does not significantly affect outcomes for retirees compared with immediate purchase of annuities at retirement.
Bottom line: There were two things I liked about Mr. Blanchett’s research: 1) He favored a dynamic withdrawal approach very similar to the approach advocated in this website and 2) depending on their preferences and circumstances, retirees should consider investment of some percentage of their retirement portfolio in annuities.
Thursday, November 5, 2015
Social Security Reform—Some Solutions are More Sustainable than Others
As discussed in my posts of March 1 and May 3 of this year, I occasionally get drawn into commenting on US Social Security System financing issues. While these issues are somewhat technical, I believe they are important and, in the long run, can affect many of the individuals who visit my site looking for advice regarding budgeting in retirement. Therefore this post will be another Social Security financing article with the purpose of warning my U.S. readers about frequently made claims regarding the long-term sustainability of specific reform proposals. As we get closer to 2034 (the trust fund exhaustion date expected for Social Security under the intermediate assumption set selected by Social Security actuaries and the System’s Trustees in the most recent Trustees’ report), we are seeing a rash of proposals to solve the System’s financial problems. Many of these proposals quantify just how much of the System’s “funding problem” will be solved by a specific reform proposal. For example, in the American Academy of Actuaries recently released “Social Security Game,” the Academy states that raising the payroll tax from 6.2% to 7.4% (for both employees and employers) “will solve 85% of the problem". Further, if you combine that change with a 1% decrease in the cost of living increase, the Social Security Game will tell you, “Congratulations, You have won the game by fixing Social Security.”
While I understand the Academy’s desire to engage the public in a discussion about Social Security’s reform options, I am concerned that statements such as these can mislead the public and our policymakers. I was frankly surprised (and more than a little disappointed) that my profession (a profession that claims to serve the public, one that stresses sustainability in our financial systems and one that has stated it “believes that any modification to the Social Security system should include “sustainable solvency” as a primary goal) is ignoring the concept of “sustainable solvency” and is claiming in this “Game” that eliminating Social Security’s current 75-year actuarial deficit will solve Social Security’s financial problems. It should be noted that the Academy is not the only organization to utilize the 75-year actuarial deficit in this manner.
While reducing the 75-year actuarial deficit is a reasonable first step, there are two problems with any proposed reform
options that simply reduce Social Security’s 75-year actuarial deficit to zero:
We need look no further than the 1983 Amendments to Social Security (which eliminated the 75-year actuarial deficit in existence at that time) for an example of how these two problems interacted to put us in the financial position in which we presently find ourselves. Social Security Administration Actuarial Note Number 2015.8 tells us that of the total increase in the 75-year actuarial deficit of 2.69% of taxable payroll since 1983, 70% of the increase (or 1.90% of taxable payroll) was attributable to changes in the valuation date (problem #1 above), leaving 30% (or .79% of payroll) attributable to all other causes. Since no action was taken in response to these emerging deficits over the past 31 years (problem #2 above), we are now looking at projected trust fund exhaustion in 2034 under the best estimate assumptions.
As a result of these two problems, Social Security is now looking at a shortfall of projected revenues compared with projected expenditures. And we have unlimited supply of possible actions that Congress can adopt to address this shortfall, generally involving some combination of revenue increases and expenditure decreases. Because it was discussed on page 25 of this year’s annual Trustees’ Report, I’m going to focus on two alternative reforms involving only tax increases. I’m doing this to illustrate reform option concepts, not to recommend that reform options should only involve tax increases. The same concepts generally apply if expenditure reductions or combinations of revenue increases and expenditure decreases are adopted.
The graph below shows two alternative tax rate scenarios that would be expected, if all the intermediate assumptions made in the 2015 Trustees’ report were exactly realized over the next 75 years, to cover projected System benefits over the next 75 years, leaving almost no trust fund at the end of 2089. Under the “wait for trust fund exhaustion” alternative, we would keep the tax rate at its current combined employer-employee level of 12.4% until 2034 at which time it would increase to 16.1% and then gradually increase thereafter (I have assumed straight-line increases) to 17.4% in 2089. I have also assumed that the necessary tax rate for years thereafter would remain at the 17.4% level. The second option shown in this graph is the “75-year solution (2015)” which reduces the 2015 75-year actuarial deficit to zero by increasing the current tax rate from 12.4% to 15.02% in 2015. Since this solution only lasts for 75 years, the graph shows that the tax rate would also need to be increased in the year 2090 to 17.4% when the trust fund accumulated under this option would be expected to be depleted. This graph illustrates a very important financial principle: the magic of compound interest. Even for a program that many experts claim is a pay-as-you-go system, you can pre-fund your liabilities. By contributing 15.02% for 75 years, you can avoid higher tax rates for the period 2035 to 2089. The concepts illustrated in this graph are also used by individuals who argue that fixing the system now can avoid higher tax rates or lower benefit levels later on. Of course this same argument can be employed by those who would like to see smaller periodic adjustments to the program rather than infrequent large increases (to address Problem #2).
In an effort to deal with Problem #1 above, the Office of the Actuary of the Social Security Administration developed the concept of “sustainable solvency.” Under this concept, “the projected trust fund ratio is positive throughout the 75-year projection period and is either stable or rising at the end of the period (emphasis added).” As with other ways to solve system problems, there are a number of ways that sustainable solvency can be achieved. For example, in addition to a 75-year solution, you could adopt additional tax rate increases that take effect 65 or 70 years from now so that the relatively low trust fund ratios at the end of the period remain stable at the end of the 75-year period. Because there exist many different ways to achieve sustainable solvency, the Trustees’ Reports do not quantify changes necessary to achieve it. Also, for this reason, organizations like the American Academy of Actuaries focus only on communicating the presumably more quantifiable 75-year solutions. It should be noted, however, that even though adoption of a reform package that achieves sustainable solvency will address Problem #1 above, it does not address Problem #2 above.
The graph below modifies the graph above by inserting a third line, labeled “sustainable solvency solution (2015)”. This line is estimated by me. As discussed above, there are many different approaches that could achieve sustainable solvency, but I have selected one (a level tax rate similar to the approach used for The Canada Pension Plan) that I would expect to meet the criteria for sustainable solvency under the assumptions described above. This approach would involve an immediate 3.6% of taxable payroll increase in the current tax rate of 12.4% to about 16%. By comparison, the 2015 Trustees’ report indicates that the shortfall over the infinite projection period is 3.9% of taxable payroll. Note also that this graph could have a fourth line representing a combination of the 75-year solution and periodic increases after 2015 to address the expected deficits that would occur as a result of Problem #1. This line would be expected to start at about the 15% of pay level and slowly increase as deficits are recognized. This fourth line would be expected to end above the sustainable solvency (2015) line and below the 75-year solution line.
Conclusion—Some Solutions are More Sustainable than Others
In its Public Policy White Paper, Sustainability in American Financial Security Programs, the Academy’s Public Interest Committee said, “Sustainability is enhanced when the funding source and the benefits promised remain balanced over the lifetime of the program.” I agree and further believe that Social Security solutions that anticipate significant tax increases in the future (other than perhaps ones to phase in tax increases over a relatively short time period) to support promised benefit levels are less sustainable than approaches that don’t. For this reason, I caution readers to question 75 (or lower)-year solutions, and, as part of the next round of system reform, I encourage policymakers to adopt an automatic approach designed to maintain the balance between system assets and liabilities in the future. As suggested in my May/June, 2015 Contingencies article, we can learn a lot about sustainable solutions in the U.S. from the actions taken almost 20 years ago to reform The Canada Pension Plan. In furtherance of its mission, I also encourage the Academy to advocate these more sustainable solutions rather than appearing to endorse problematic 75-year “solutions” in their “Game.”
While I understand the Academy’s desire to engage the public in a discussion about Social Security’s reform options, I am concerned that statements such as these can mislead the public and our policymakers. I was frankly surprised (and more than a little disappointed) that my profession (a profession that claims to serve the public, one that stresses sustainability in our financial systems and one that has stated it “believes that any modification to the Social Security system should include “sustainable solvency” as a primary goal) is ignoring the concept of “sustainable solvency” and is claiming in this “Game” that eliminating Social Security’s current 75-year actuarial deficit will solve Social Security’s financial problems. It should be noted that the Academy is not the only organization to utilize the 75-year actuarial deficit in this manner.
While reducing the 75-year actuarial deficit is a reasonable first step, there are two problems with any proposed reform
options that simply reduce Social Security’s 75-year actuarial deficit to zero:
- Given the projected costs of the program, limiting the actuarial balance calculation to 75 years ignores projected annual deficits expected to occur after the end of the 75-year projection period. Over time, these deficits will emerge in the actuary’s annual calculations.
- There exists no process in current law to automatically adjust the System’s tax rates to maintain a balance between system assets and system liabilities. Imbalances (in the form of deficits in the annually calculated 75-year actuarial balance) may occur as a result of the previously unrecognized deficits mentioned in Problem #1 above, or because of changes in assumptions, experience losses or gains, or from other sources.
We need look no further than the 1983 Amendments to Social Security (which eliminated the 75-year actuarial deficit in existence at that time) for an example of how these two problems interacted to put us in the financial position in which we presently find ourselves. Social Security Administration Actuarial Note Number 2015.8 tells us that of the total increase in the 75-year actuarial deficit of 2.69% of taxable payroll since 1983, 70% of the increase (or 1.90% of taxable payroll) was attributable to changes in the valuation date (problem #1 above), leaving 30% (or .79% of payroll) attributable to all other causes. Since no action was taken in response to these emerging deficits over the past 31 years (problem #2 above), we are now looking at projected trust fund exhaustion in 2034 under the best estimate assumptions.
As a result of these two problems, Social Security is now looking at a shortfall of projected revenues compared with projected expenditures. And we have unlimited supply of possible actions that Congress can adopt to address this shortfall, generally involving some combination of revenue increases and expenditure decreases. Because it was discussed on page 25 of this year’s annual Trustees’ Report, I’m going to focus on two alternative reforms involving only tax increases. I’m doing this to illustrate reform option concepts, not to recommend that reform options should only involve tax increases. The same concepts generally apply if expenditure reductions or combinations of revenue increases and expenditure decreases are adopted.
The graph below shows two alternative tax rate scenarios that would be expected, if all the intermediate assumptions made in the 2015 Trustees’ report were exactly realized over the next 75 years, to cover projected System benefits over the next 75 years, leaving almost no trust fund at the end of 2089. Under the “wait for trust fund exhaustion” alternative, we would keep the tax rate at its current combined employer-employee level of 12.4% until 2034 at which time it would increase to 16.1% and then gradually increase thereafter (I have assumed straight-line increases) to 17.4% in 2089. I have also assumed that the necessary tax rate for years thereafter would remain at the 17.4% level. The second option shown in this graph is the “75-year solution (2015)” which reduces the 2015 75-year actuarial deficit to zero by increasing the current tax rate from 12.4% to 15.02% in 2015. Since this solution only lasts for 75 years, the graph shows that the tax rate would also need to be increased in the year 2090 to 17.4% when the trust fund accumulated under this option would be expected to be depleted. This graph illustrates a very important financial principle: the magic of compound interest. Even for a program that many experts claim is a pay-as-you-go system, you can pre-fund your liabilities. By contributing 15.02% for 75 years, you can avoid higher tax rates for the period 2035 to 2089. The concepts illustrated in this graph are also used by individuals who argue that fixing the system now can avoid higher tax rates or lower benefit levels later on. Of course this same argument can be employed by those who would like to see smaller periodic adjustments to the program rather than infrequent large increases (to address Problem #2).
![]() |
(click to enlarge) |
In an effort to deal with Problem #1 above, the Office of the Actuary of the Social Security Administration developed the concept of “sustainable solvency.” Under this concept, “the projected trust fund ratio is positive throughout the 75-year projection period and is either stable or rising at the end of the period (emphasis added).” As with other ways to solve system problems, there are a number of ways that sustainable solvency can be achieved. For example, in addition to a 75-year solution, you could adopt additional tax rate increases that take effect 65 or 70 years from now so that the relatively low trust fund ratios at the end of the period remain stable at the end of the 75-year period. Because there exist many different ways to achieve sustainable solvency, the Trustees’ Reports do not quantify changes necessary to achieve it. Also, for this reason, organizations like the American Academy of Actuaries focus only on communicating the presumably more quantifiable 75-year solutions. It should be noted, however, that even though adoption of a reform package that achieves sustainable solvency will address Problem #1 above, it does not address Problem #2 above.
The graph below modifies the graph above by inserting a third line, labeled “sustainable solvency solution (2015)”. This line is estimated by me. As discussed above, there are many different approaches that could achieve sustainable solvency, but I have selected one (a level tax rate similar to the approach used for The Canada Pension Plan) that I would expect to meet the criteria for sustainable solvency under the assumptions described above. This approach would involve an immediate 3.6% of taxable payroll increase in the current tax rate of 12.4% to about 16%. By comparison, the 2015 Trustees’ report indicates that the shortfall over the infinite projection period is 3.9% of taxable payroll. Note also that this graph could have a fourth line representing a combination of the 75-year solution and periodic increases after 2015 to address the expected deficits that would occur as a result of Problem #1. This line would be expected to start at about the 15% of pay level and slowly increase as deficits are recognized. This fourth line would be expected to end above the sustainable solvency (2015) line and below the 75-year solution line.
![]() |
(click to enlarge) |
Conclusion—Some Solutions are More Sustainable than Others
In its Public Policy White Paper, Sustainability in American Financial Security Programs, the Academy’s Public Interest Committee said, “Sustainability is enhanced when the funding source and the benefits promised remain balanced over the lifetime of the program.” I agree and further believe that Social Security solutions that anticipate significant tax increases in the future (other than perhaps ones to phase in tax increases over a relatively short time period) to support promised benefit levels are less sustainable than approaches that don’t. For this reason, I caution readers to question 75 (or lower)-year solutions, and, as part of the next round of system reform, I encourage policymakers to adopt an automatic approach designed to maintain the balance between system assets and liabilities in the future. As suggested in my May/June, 2015 Contingencies article, we can learn a lot about sustainable solutions in the U.S. from the actions taken almost 20 years ago to reform The Canada Pension Plan. In furtherance of its mission, I also encourage the Academy to advocate these more sustainable solutions rather than appearing to endorse problematic 75-year “solutions” in their “Game.”
Saturday, October 31, 2015
Actuaries Release Five New Issue Briefs on Retiree Lifetime Income
As a follow-up to their 2013 Public Policy Discussion Paper, “Risky Business—Living Longer Without Income for Life” (discussed in our post of June 20, 2013), the American Academy of Actuaries’ Lifetime Income Risk Joint Task Force recently released a flurry of Issue Briefs on Retiree Lifetime Income. The five issue briefs are titled,
The stated goal of the Academy’s Task Force is to educate the public, financial advisors, employers, the media, lawmakers and regulators on the risk of inadequate guaranteed lifetime income. As may be expected from a group of actuaries with this goal, the issue briefs tend to stress the advantages of risk sharing (or risk pooling) arrangements (annuities and defined benefit pension benefits). However, this most recent batch of issue briefs does not focus exclusively on the advantages of annuity products and the disadvantages of structured withdrawal programs. They do acknowledge that there can be advantages of combining the two approaches. For example the following guidance is contained in the Actuarial Considerations for Financial Advisers brief:
“A judicious use of pooling-based solutions, integrated with appropriate investment strategies, can often yield a more favorable financial result than one that fails to take pooling into appropriate consideration.”
I was also pleased to see that the Financial Advisers brief included the following recommended task, which is a common theme expressed in my website
“Assuring that recommended systematic withdrawal strategies meet client objectives and also appropriately reflect the existence or absence of pension benefits or insurance-based solutions that incorporate risk-pooling features.”
Sharp-eyed readers who go to the Task Force website may see my name included as a Task Force member. Yes I did recently join this group, but for the most part, most of these Issue Briefs were drafted prior to my arrival.
- Retiree Lifetime Income: Choices and Considerations
- Retiree Lifetime Income: Product Comparisons
- Risky Business: Living Longer Without Income for Life—Legislative and Regulatory Issues
- Risky Business: Living Longer Without Income for Life—Actuarial Considerations for Financial Advisers, and
- Risky Business: Living Longer Without Income for Life—Information for Current and Future Retirees
The stated goal of the Academy’s Task Force is to educate the public, financial advisors, employers, the media, lawmakers and regulators on the risk of inadequate guaranteed lifetime income. As may be expected from a group of actuaries with this goal, the issue briefs tend to stress the advantages of risk sharing (or risk pooling) arrangements (annuities and defined benefit pension benefits). However, this most recent batch of issue briefs does not focus exclusively on the advantages of annuity products and the disadvantages of structured withdrawal programs. They do acknowledge that there can be advantages of combining the two approaches. For example the following guidance is contained in the Actuarial Considerations for Financial Advisers brief:
“A judicious use of pooling-based solutions, integrated with appropriate investment strategies, can often yield a more favorable financial result than one that fails to take pooling into appropriate consideration.”
I was also pleased to see that the Financial Advisers brief included the following recommended task, which is a common theme expressed in my website
“Assuring that recommended systematic withdrawal strategies meet client objectives and also appropriately reflect the existence or absence of pension benefits or insurance-based solutions that incorporate risk-pooling features.”
Sharp-eyed readers who go to the Task Force website may see my name included as a Task Force member. Yes I did recently join this group, but for the most part, most of these Issue Briefs were drafted prior to my arrival.
Saturday, October 24, 2015
Does New Math Clearly Demonstrate that People Should Delay Commencement of Social Security Benefits When Possible?
Apologies to my non-US readers as I will once again take on the subject of when to commence US Social Security benefits. This post is in response to the October 23 article in The Wall Street Journal entitled, "The New Math of Delaying Social Security Benefits”, in which Dr. Pfau concludes, “the math is clear: People should delay claiming when possible.”
As I have discussed in several prior posts (most recently in posts of September 25, 2015, April 16, 2015 and August 9, 2014) and based on the “old math” built into the simple Social Security Bridge spreadsheet on this website, deferring commencement of Social Security benefits can be a reasonably good strategy for many individuals, but it may not be all that it is cracked up to be by the media experts.
I’m going to use the same example person in this post as Dr. Pfau used in his article (which I suggest that you read because I’m not going to repeat the entire example here). His example person sets aside assets of $316,800 in a non-interest bearing account to pay herself $39,600 per year (the age 70 Social Security benefit without CPI increases) during the eight year bridge period (from age 62 to age 69) during which no Social Security benefits are paid. He then determines that the initial withdrawal rate at age 62 from remaining assets necessary plus the withdrawals from this artificial Social Security replacement account to meet a $60,000 annual real dollar total income level is only 4.22% vs. a 4.69% initial withdrawal rate necessary to meet the $60,000 total income level if she commences her Social Security benefits at age 62. From this comparison of initial age 62 withdrawal rates, Dr. Pfau concludes that it is financially advantages for everyone to defer commencement of Social Security from age 62 until age 70.
If we assume inflation of 2.5% per year and we assume that the example retiree wishes to pay herself the expected age 70 Social Security benefit in real dollars each year during the bridge period, she will need to set aside assets of $345,951. Under these assumptions, the initial age 62 withdrawal percentage to achieve the $60,000 income target will be 4.49% ($60,000 – $39,600)/ ($800,000 - $345,951) vs. the 4.69% withdrawal rate if she commenced Social Security at age 62. This example still favors the deferral strategy, but not by quite as much.
If we also assume investment return of 4.5% per annum on the example retiree’s assets not set aside for bridge purposes, at age 70, she will have remaining assets of $428,583 to go with her Social Security benefit of $48,249 ($39,600 plus eight years of CPI increases of 2.5% per annum). By comparison, if she commenced benefits at age 62, she would have $738,560 of remaining assets at age 70 and a Social Security benefit of $27,414. Thus, under these assumptions, she effectively spends $309,977 ($738,560 - $428,583) of her expected assets at age 70 ($35,974 less than the $345,951 she set aside) to obtain an additional $20,835 ($48,249 - $27,414) of fully CPI-indexed Social Security benefits commencing at age 70.
As noted in prior posts on this subject, deferring commencement of Social Security can increase total retirement income under most reasonable assumptions. This strategy also adds inflation protection and can provide larger benefits to your spouse. If you want to retire and adopt the commencement deferral strategy, you have to be willing to dip into your accumulated savings to make it work (and therefore this strategy may involve loss of some spending flexibility). The degree of success of the commencement deferral strategy will depend on the investment return you could have earned on the "bridge payments" you withdraw from your accumulated savings, the rate of future inflation, how long you live and how much of your accumulated savings you spend during the bridge period. Assuming Social Security law remains unchanged, it can be an effective way to mitigate inflation risk, investment risk, and longevity risk. In a very real sense, the decision to defer is analogous to using your savings to purchase additional longevity insurance/real annuity income. However, under most reasonable assumption scenarios, you aren’t likely to see the increases in total retirement income that you might have expected from reading articles on this subject by the retirement experts.
I recommend that retirees who are reasonably comfortable spending a significant portion of their accumulated savings up front during the bridge period consider the commencement deferral strategy. On the other hand, I am also sensitive to retirees who could have made this decision but didn’t or who are just not comfortable with this strategy. To them I say, Don’t listen to those experts who say that not deferring until age 70 is one of the biggest mistakes you can make in retirement. Move on with your life based on the decision you made (or will make). If it is indeed a mistake not to defer, it is probably not the biggest mistake you will make in retirement.
As with all my prior posts on this subject, I (and Dr. Pfau in his article) looked at non-married individuals. The factors involved in a decision to defer can be different for a married individual under current law.
As I have discussed in several prior posts (most recently in posts of September 25, 2015, April 16, 2015 and August 9, 2014) and based on the “old math” built into the simple Social Security Bridge spreadsheet on this website, deferring commencement of Social Security benefits can be a reasonably good strategy for many individuals, but it may not be all that it is cracked up to be by the media experts.
I’m going to use the same example person in this post as Dr. Pfau used in his article (which I suggest that you read because I’m not going to repeat the entire example here). His example person sets aside assets of $316,800 in a non-interest bearing account to pay herself $39,600 per year (the age 70 Social Security benefit without CPI increases) during the eight year bridge period (from age 62 to age 69) during which no Social Security benefits are paid. He then determines that the initial withdrawal rate at age 62 from remaining assets necessary plus the withdrawals from this artificial Social Security replacement account to meet a $60,000 annual real dollar total income level is only 4.22% vs. a 4.69% initial withdrawal rate necessary to meet the $60,000 total income level if she commences her Social Security benefits at age 62. From this comparison of initial age 62 withdrawal rates, Dr. Pfau concludes that it is financially advantages for everyone to defer commencement of Social Security from age 62 until age 70.
If we assume inflation of 2.5% per year and we assume that the example retiree wishes to pay herself the expected age 70 Social Security benefit in real dollars each year during the bridge period, she will need to set aside assets of $345,951. Under these assumptions, the initial age 62 withdrawal percentage to achieve the $60,000 income target will be 4.49% ($60,000 – $39,600)/ ($800,000 - $345,951) vs. the 4.69% withdrawal rate if she commenced Social Security at age 62. This example still favors the deferral strategy, but not by quite as much.
If we also assume investment return of 4.5% per annum on the example retiree’s assets not set aside for bridge purposes, at age 70, she will have remaining assets of $428,583 to go with her Social Security benefit of $48,249 ($39,600 plus eight years of CPI increases of 2.5% per annum). By comparison, if she commenced benefits at age 62, she would have $738,560 of remaining assets at age 70 and a Social Security benefit of $27,414. Thus, under these assumptions, she effectively spends $309,977 ($738,560 - $428,583) of her expected assets at age 70 ($35,974 less than the $345,951 she set aside) to obtain an additional $20,835 ($48,249 - $27,414) of fully CPI-indexed Social Security benefits commencing at age 70.
As noted in prior posts on this subject, deferring commencement of Social Security can increase total retirement income under most reasonable assumptions. This strategy also adds inflation protection and can provide larger benefits to your spouse. If you want to retire and adopt the commencement deferral strategy, you have to be willing to dip into your accumulated savings to make it work (and therefore this strategy may involve loss of some spending flexibility). The degree of success of the commencement deferral strategy will depend on the investment return you could have earned on the "bridge payments" you withdraw from your accumulated savings, the rate of future inflation, how long you live and how much of your accumulated savings you spend during the bridge period. Assuming Social Security law remains unchanged, it can be an effective way to mitigate inflation risk, investment risk, and longevity risk. In a very real sense, the decision to defer is analogous to using your savings to purchase additional longevity insurance/real annuity income. However, under most reasonable assumption scenarios, you aren’t likely to see the increases in total retirement income that you might have expected from reading articles on this subject by the retirement experts.
I recommend that retirees who are reasonably comfortable spending a significant portion of their accumulated savings up front during the bridge period consider the commencement deferral strategy. On the other hand, I am also sensitive to retirees who could have made this decision but didn’t or who are just not comfortable with this strategy. To them I say, Don’t listen to those experts who say that not deferring until age 70 is one of the biggest mistakes you can make in retirement. Move on with your life based on the decision you made (or will make). If it is indeed a mistake not to defer, it is probably not the biggest mistake you will make in retirement.
As with all my prior posts on this subject, I (and Dr. Pfau in his article) looked at non-married individuals. The factors involved in a decision to defer can be different for a married individual under current law.
Saturday, October 17, 2015
All About that Budget
If I had to pick a theme song for this website, I guess I would have to consider Meghan Trainor’s popular song with a small modification. While Meghan sings, “Because you know I’m all about that bass”, this website is all about a different “B” word—“Budget.” Yes, the primary purpose of this website is to help retirees develop a reasonable spending budget. Pretty much this entire website is devoted to this task; a task that a lot of retirees don’t even bother with, or if they do bother with it, they frequently ignore it when it comes to making spending decisions. Does the fact that a lot of retirees don’t develop a budget or ignore their budget bother me? Not particularly. Unlike many experts who think that most retirees aren’t smart enough or motivated enough to manage their own money, I believe that most retirees possess the necessary skills to successfully manage their finances in retirement, much like they successfully managed their finances when they were employed. Of course, for those retirees who can afford one, a financial advisor can be very helpful in this process. However, when push comes to shove, it is you, Mr. or Ms. Retiree, who are ultimately responsible for making the investment and spending decisions that affect your financial situation during your retirement. If you are reading this post, I hope it is because you are interested in learning about and taking advantage of the benefits of having a reasonable spending budget.
You won’t find anything in this website that suggests how much of your accumulated savings or other sources of retirement income you should spend each year. As noted above, that decision is yours based on your own personal situation. I’m not going to chastise you for spending more (or less) that the budget amount you may develop using the Actuarial Approach. In fact, it would be unusual if you did spend exactly the amount that you budgeted each year. However, one of the primary benefits of developing a spending budget is to help you make your spending decisions.
You also won’t find anything in this website that suggests that you should develop a spending budget any more frequently than annually. There may be reasons why you may wish to develop a monthly spending budget (for example if you are trying to reduce your spending), but again, I will leave that decision up to you.
While I think it is worthwhile to track actual spending for the year to compare it with the spending budget, doing so is a fair amount of work that may not provide a lot of value to you. There are software programs that can help you with this task, but again, tracking actual spending can be time-consuming and it is not necessary to keep your budgeting on track. Under the Actuarial Approach, simply comparing your actual end of year assets with your expected end of year assets will give you an indication of the total gain or loss for the year resulting from the combination of spending deviations and investment deviations. As indicated in my September 4, 2015 post, it may make sense during the middle of a year to compare actual assets with expected end-of-year assets to see how you are doing during the year for the purpose of helping you make spending decisions for the rest of the year.
I also think it can be worthwhile to develop separate budgets for different types of expenses. In prior posts, I have encouraged you to develop separate budgets for such different types of expenses as essential non-medical expenses, essential medical expenses, bequest motive/end-of-life expenses, other unexpected expenses and non-essential expenses. The reason for doing this is that you may have different goals and investment strategies for these different types of expenses that may require different approaches.
Prior posts have also indicated why I think it is important to develop a spending budget that reflects the existence of other sources of retirement income that you may have. Most other withdrawal strategies simply provide a suggested way to “tap your savings” and fail to suggest how to develop a reasonable spending budget (or budgets).
While not every financial expert believes that budgets are essential (especially monthly budgets), many experts do. Here are a couple of recent articles touting some of the benefits of developing a budget.
5 Ways to Save Money During Retirement (US News)
8 Things Not to Do in Retirement (GoBankingRates)
You won’t find anything in this website that suggests how much of your accumulated savings or other sources of retirement income you should spend each year. As noted above, that decision is yours based on your own personal situation. I’m not going to chastise you for spending more (or less) that the budget amount you may develop using the Actuarial Approach. In fact, it would be unusual if you did spend exactly the amount that you budgeted each year. However, one of the primary benefits of developing a spending budget is to help you make your spending decisions.
You also won’t find anything in this website that suggests that you should develop a spending budget any more frequently than annually. There may be reasons why you may wish to develop a monthly spending budget (for example if you are trying to reduce your spending), but again, I will leave that decision up to you.
While I think it is worthwhile to track actual spending for the year to compare it with the spending budget, doing so is a fair amount of work that may not provide a lot of value to you. There are software programs that can help you with this task, but again, tracking actual spending can be time-consuming and it is not necessary to keep your budgeting on track. Under the Actuarial Approach, simply comparing your actual end of year assets with your expected end of year assets will give you an indication of the total gain or loss for the year resulting from the combination of spending deviations and investment deviations. As indicated in my September 4, 2015 post, it may make sense during the middle of a year to compare actual assets with expected end-of-year assets to see how you are doing during the year for the purpose of helping you make spending decisions for the rest of the year.
I also think it can be worthwhile to develop separate budgets for different types of expenses. In prior posts, I have encouraged you to develop separate budgets for such different types of expenses as essential non-medical expenses, essential medical expenses, bequest motive/end-of-life expenses, other unexpected expenses and non-essential expenses. The reason for doing this is that you may have different goals and investment strategies for these different types of expenses that may require different approaches.
Prior posts have also indicated why I think it is important to develop a spending budget that reflects the existence of other sources of retirement income that you may have. Most other withdrawal strategies simply provide a suggested way to “tap your savings” and fail to suggest how to develop a reasonable spending budget (or budgets).
While not every financial expert believes that budgets are essential (especially monthly budgets), many experts do. Here are a couple of recent articles touting some of the benefits of developing a budget.
5 Ways to Save Money During Retirement (US News)
8 Things Not to Do in Retirement (GoBankingRates)
Thursday, October 15, 2015
Making Sense Out of Variable Spending Strategies for Retirees?
In his October 2, 2015 blog post, Dr. Wade Pfau, Professor of Retirement Income at The American College, reprinted his article from the Journal of Financial Planning, Making Sense Out of Variable Spending Strategies for Retirees. The stated purpose of this article was to “assist financial planners and their clients in figuring out which sort of variable spending strategy will be most appropriate for their situation [by using] simple metrics to evaluate and compare strategies.” See my post of March 19th of this year for my initial thoughts on this paper. Today’s post will supplement my earlier post with additional thoughts on this article.
Perhaps the most interesting part of Dr. Pfau’s article is his suggestion that financial advisors use his “XYZ Formula” approach to help clients select a combination budget setting strategy (variable spending strategy) and investment strategy. Under this approach, the financial advisor uses Monte Carlo modeling and the client’s specific information to help the client select the combination budget setting and investment strategy that has an “X% probability that spending falls below a threshold of $Y (in inflation-adjusted terms) by year Z of retirement”, where the client (with the advisor’s help) chooses the values of X, Y and Z, presumably in accordance with the client’s risk preferences. The XYZ formula approach assumes that the client’s spending will exactly equal the client’s spending budget so determined each year.
Even though it is based on the unrealistic assumption that retiree spending will actually equal the spending budget resulting from application of variable spending strategy, I believe that Dr. Pfau’s approach can provide some value to retirees. However, rather than providing a broad analysis of various combinations of budget setting strategies and investment strategies for hypothetical clients with different situations, Dr. Pfau instead holds investment allocations constant, fixes values of X,Y and Z and looks at a client that (with one notable exception) has no pension/annuity income. The purpose of fixing these items was presumably to isolate differences attributable to differences inherent in the variable spending strategies.
I was pleased to see the Actuarial Approach advocated in this website included in Dr. Pfau’s list of examined variable rate strategies (albeit grouped with other so-called actuarial strategies). I was also pleased that Dr. Pfau concluded, “The actuarial methods were found to spend down wealth more efficiently.” However, I feel compelled in this post to (i) respond to a specific comment made in the article about application of smoothing to my approach and (ii) point out why my approach is superior to the “PMT approach” with which my approach was grouped.
Smoothing
In his article, Dr. Pfau says, “Steiner (2014) suggested that users may smooth spending adjustments relative to the changes implied by this formula. Not all would agree, as Waring and Siegel (2015) noted that a less volatile asset allocation is a safer way to smooth spending fluctuations.” While I certainly don’t have a problem with the position that a less volatile asset allocation is a reasonable way to manage volatility in spending budgets, I believe Waring and Siegel’s suggestion that spending budgets not be smoothed is ridiculous. For most retirees, a spending budget is simply a suggestion as to how much the retiree may want to spend for the year. Only retirement academics and other Monte Carlo modelling advocates assume that retirees will actually spend their spending budget each year (and only as a calculation expediency). It therefore makes no sense to me to require a spending budget to be based on strict (non-smoothed) application of a formula if the retiree can then choose to spend whatever he or she wants.
Actuarial Approach vs. PMT Approach
Waring and Siegel’s ARVA (PMT) approach is essentially mathematically equivalent to the simple spreadsheet included in my website if the retiree has no fixed dollar pension or annuity income. If the retiree has a fixed dollar pension benefit, a fixed dollar immediate annuity or a fixed dollar deferred annuity, the PMT approach can’t properly handle it.
It is ironic to me that the approach that appears to produce the most favorable results in Dr. Pfau’s article (at least in terms of initial spending rates under the given XYZ specifications) is the “Annuitize Floor and Aggressive Discretionary Spending” approach. This isn’t really a different variable rate spending approach, but rather a combination of a different investment strategy (partial annuitization) with the Guyton decision rules. As noted in previous posts (most recently my post of April 26, 2015), I’m not a big fan of the Guyton decision rules, but inclusion of this final option does illustrate the potential benefits of partial annuitization for risk averse clients. It also indirectly points out the importance of using a variable spending strategy that properly coordinates with fixed dollar pension and annuity benefits. And once again, I will end a post by noting that the Actuarial Approach is the only one of the variable spending strategies listed in Dr. Pfau’s article that does this.
Perhaps the most interesting part of Dr. Pfau’s article is his suggestion that financial advisors use his “XYZ Formula” approach to help clients select a combination budget setting strategy (variable spending strategy) and investment strategy. Under this approach, the financial advisor uses Monte Carlo modeling and the client’s specific information to help the client select the combination budget setting and investment strategy that has an “X% probability that spending falls below a threshold of $Y (in inflation-adjusted terms) by year Z of retirement”, where the client (with the advisor’s help) chooses the values of X, Y and Z, presumably in accordance with the client’s risk preferences. The XYZ formula approach assumes that the client’s spending will exactly equal the client’s spending budget so determined each year.
Even though it is based on the unrealistic assumption that retiree spending will actually equal the spending budget resulting from application of variable spending strategy, I believe that Dr. Pfau’s approach can provide some value to retirees. However, rather than providing a broad analysis of various combinations of budget setting strategies and investment strategies for hypothetical clients with different situations, Dr. Pfau instead holds investment allocations constant, fixes values of X,Y and Z and looks at a client that (with one notable exception) has no pension/annuity income. The purpose of fixing these items was presumably to isolate differences attributable to differences inherent in the variable spending strategies.
I was pleased to see the Actuarial Approach advocated in this website included in Dr. Pfau’s list of examined variable rate strategies (albeit grouped with other so-called actuarial strategies). I was also pleased that Dr. Pfau concluded, “The actuarial methods were found to spend down wealth more efficiently.” However, I feel compelled in this post to (i) respond to a specific comment made in the article about application of smoothing to my approach and (ii) point out why my approach is superior to the “PMT approach” with which my approach was grouped.
Smoothing
In his article, Dr. Pfau says, “Steiner (2014) suggested that users may smooth spending adjustments relative to the changes implied by this formula. Not all would agree, as Waring and Siegel (2015) noted that a less volatile asset allocation is a safer way to smooth spending fluctuations.” While I certainly don’t have a problem with the position that a less volatile asset allocation is a reasonable way to manage volatility in spending budgets, I believe Waring and Siegel’s suggestion that spending budgets not be smoothed is ridiculous. For most retirees, a spending budget is simply a suggestion as to how much the retiree may want to spend for the year. Only retirement academics and other Monte Carlo modelling advocates assume that retirees will actually spend their spending budget each year (and only as a calculation expediency). It therefore makes no sense to me to require a spending budget to be based on strict (non-smoothed) application of a formula if the retiree can then choose to spend whatever he or she wants.
Actuarial Approach vs. PMT Approach
Waring and Siegel’s ARVA (PMT) approach is essentially mathematically equivalent to the simple spreadsheet included in my website if the retiree has no fixed dollar pension or annuity income. If the retiree has a fixed dollar pension benefit, a fixed dollar immediate annuity or a fixed dollar deferred annuity, the PMT approach can’t properly handle it.
It is ironic to me that the approach that appears to produce the most favorable results in Dr. Pfau’s article (at least in terms of initial spending rates under the given XYZ specifications) is the “Annuitize Floor and Aggressive Discretionary Spending” approach. This isn’t really a different variable rate spending approach, but rather a combination of a different investment strategy (partial annuitization) with the Guyton decision rules. As noted in previous posts (most recently my post of April 26, 2015), I’m not a big fan of the Guyton decision rules, but inclusion of this final option does illustrate the potential benefits of partial annuitization for risk averse clients. It also indirectly points out the importance of using a variable spending strategy that properly coordinates with fixed dollar pension and annuity benefits. And once again, I will end a post by noting that the Actuarial Approach is the only one of the variable spending strategies listed in Dr. Pfau’s article that does this.
Monday, October 12, 2015
Fear of Outliving Your Savings vs. Fear of Not Spending Enough—Finding an Appropriate Balance
In his September 29 article for US News, Why You Won’t Run Out of Money in Retirement, David Ning outlines several safeguards that he believes “will prevent you from spending your savings too quickly.” He indicates that you “aren’t likely to completely run out of money in retirement,” and therefore you shouldn’t “let the fear of outliving your savings prevent you from enjoying retirement.” One of the safeguards recommended by Mr. Ning is to withdraw only 3% or 4% of accumulated savings each year.
I agree with Mr. Ning that retirees shouldn’t let the fear of outliving their savings prevent them from enjoying retirement. On the other hand, simply taking steps to make sure that you don’t spend your savings too quickly (by using a conservative 3% or 4% withdrawal rate) is only part of the equation for enjoying retirement. Another critical part of this equation is spending enough each year to maintain a certain standard of living, including spending on non-essential items. Therefore, what retirees really need is a Goldilocks-type solution that involves not only not spending too much but also not spending too little. Unfortunately, since no one knows, for certain, things like how long you will live, what your investments will earn, what future inflation will be, etc., there can be no such Goldilocks solution.
The Actuarial Approach discussed in this website attempts to help retirees find the appropriate balance between spending too much and spending too little. If you use our recommended assumptions to develop some or all of your annual spending budget and invest your accumulated savings reasonably well, you will likely end up with more assets than you desire upon your death (even though withdrawal rates for retirees with no pension/annuity income and no amounts to be left to heirs under the Actuarial Approach will exceed 6% at ages above 75, compared with the 3% or 4% withdrawal rate suggested by Mr. Ning.)
More effective safeguards to balancing not spending too much and not spending too little (as well as achieving ancillary goals such as: (i) having relatively predictable and stable inflation adjusted income from year to year, (ii) having spending flexibility to meet unforeseen expenses, (iii) maximizing the general level of spendable income and (iv) not leaving too much unspent upon death) include using the Actuarial Approach to develop separate spending budgets for essential expenses, non-essential expenses, long-term care/other end of life expenses, and unexpected expenses with appropriate investment strategies for the funds dedicated to these separate spending budgets as discussed in recent posts.
I agree with Mr. Ning that retirees shouldn’t let the fear of outliving their savings prevent them from enjoying retirement. On the other hand, simply taking steps to make sure that you don’t spend your savings too quickly (by using a conservative 3% or 4% withdrawal rate) is only part of the equation for enjoying retirement. Another critical part of this equation is spending enough each year to maintain a certain standard of living, including spending on non-essential items. Therefore, what retirees really need is a Goldilocks-type solution that involves not only not spending too much but also not spending too little. Unfortunately, since no one knows, for certain, things like how long you will live, what your investments will earn, what future inflation will be, etc., there can be no such Goldilocks solution.
The Actuarial Approach discussed in this website attempts to help retirees find the appropriate balance between spending too much and spending too little. If you use our recommended assumptions to develop some or all of your annual spending budget and invest your accumulated savings reasonably well, you will likely end up with more assets than you desire upon your death (even though withdrawal rates for retirees with no pension/annuity income and no amounts to be left to heirs under the Actuarial Approach will exceed 6% at ages above 75, compared with the 3% or 4% withdrawal rate suggested by Mr. Ning.)
More effective safeguards to balancing not spending too much and not spending too little (as well as achieving ancillary goals such as: (i) having relatively predictable and stable inflation adjusted income from year to year, (ii) having spending flexibility to meet unforeseen expenses, (iii) maximizing the general level of spendable income and (iv) not leaving too much unspent upon death) include using the Actuarial Approach to develop separate spending budgets for essential expenses, non-essential expenses, long-term care/other end of life expenses, and unexpected expenses with appropriate investment strategies for the funds dedicated to these separate spending budgets as discussed in recent posts.
Friday, September 25, 2015
Another Look at Deferral of Commencement of Social Security Benefits
My retired neighbor, Leon, is turning age 62 in the near future. A couple of days ago, when I was out performing what our dog believes is my primary purpose in life (being his personal bathroom attendant), Leon asked me for my thoughts about whether he should defer commencement of his Social Security benefit. Like everyone else, he had read many articles from experts who strongly recommend that retirees defer commencement of their Social Security benefits. Leon pointed me to Michael Kitces’ April 2, 2014 post where Michael said, “the decision to delay Social Security actually represents an astonishingly valuable ‘investment return’.” Leon had also done his “breakeven” calculations.
I told Leon that while deferring commencement of Social Security could be financially advantageous, I believed (and my prior posts on this subject have indicated) that deferral is not necessarily a “no-brainer.” The effectiveness of the deferral strategy depends on a number of considerations, including: 1) how long you will live, 2) how much savings you will use to “bridge” the period of deferral, 3) what investment return you could earn on your savings and 4) the rate of future inflation.
The table below shows the increase/(decrease) in the present value of a retiree’s spendable income associated with deferring a $750 per month Social Security benefit payable at age 62 until age 70 vs. commencing the benefit at age 62 assuming various ages of death. The table uses the same assumptions and hypothetical retiree as used in Mr. Kitces’ article. The calculations were performed using the Social Security Bridge spreadsheet from this website.
The table shows that under these assumptions, individuals who live longer will benefit financially by deferring commencement of the benefit until age 70 vs. commencing at age 62, while those with shorter lives will benefit financially by commencing the benefit at age 62. It also shows that even those individuals who choose to defer commencement until age 70 and live until age 97 are not expected to be huge winners under the assumptions used to develop this table.
The table also provides survival probabilities to the various ages based on the Society of Actuaries’ 2012 Individual Annuitant Mortality Table with 1% mortality improvement. This mortality table (and the probabilities of survival) is available in our website in the “other calculators and tools” section. It should be noted that this table represents mortality experience of individuals who purchased annuities and as such is more conservative (longer life expectancy) than general population mortality. The probabilities of survival to age 97 for both males and females were not available from the tool on our website and have been estimated by me.
One of the big differences between Mr. Kitces calculations and mine has to do with the amount of money spent by the hypothetical retiree from his accumulated savings during the eight year deferral period. Mr. Kitces assumes the retiree will spend $750 per month in the first year of deferral and $922 in the seventh year ($750 increased with 7 years of inflation at 3% per year), whereas I have assumed that the retiree does not want to have a big jump in spendable income in year 8 and will spend the same real dollar amount of $1,672 the retiree expects to receive at age 70 during each year of the deferral ($1,320 per month in the first year and $1,624 per month in the 7th year). The cost of deferrals (the present value of withdrawals from savings) under Mr. Kitces methodology is $65,258 while under my methodology, it is $114,853. This is why deferring commencement looks so much more favorable in Mr. Kitces article (if you spend less today, you can spend more later all things being equal). Of course, it would look even more favorable if the hypothetical retiree decided not to withdraw any amounts during the deferral period.
As I told Leon, I’m not going to make a recommendation one way or another on whether retirees should defer commencement of Social Security. It is an individual decision that involves many factors. If you are willing to defer and don’t spend too much of your accumulated savings during the bridge period, you can generally increase your spendable income in your later years.
I told Leon that while deferring commencement of Social Security could be financially advantageous, I believed (and my prior posts on this subject have indicated) that deferral is not necessarily a “no-brainer.” The effectiveness of the deferral strategy depends on a number of considerations, including: 1) how long you will live, 2) how much savings you will use to “bridge” the period of deferral, 3) what investment return you could earn on your savings and 4) the rate of future inflation.
The table below shows the increase/(decrease) in the present value of a retiree’s spendable income associated with deferring a $750 per month Social Security benefit payable at age 62 until age 70 vs. commencing the benefit at age 62 assuming various ages of death. The table uses the same assumptions and hypothetical retiree as used in Mr. Kitces’ article. The calculations were performed using the Social Security Bridge spreadsheet from this website.
![]() |
(click to enlarge) |
The table shows that under these assumptions, individuals who live longer will benefit financially by deferring commencement of the benefit until age 70 vs. commencing at age 62, while those with shorter lives will benefit financially by commencing the benefit at age 62. It also shows that even those individuals who choose to defer commencement until age 70 and live until age 97 are not expected to be huge winners under the assumptions used to develop this table.
The table also provides survival probabilities to the various ages based on the Society of Actuaries’ 2012 Individual Annuitant Mortality Table with 1% mortality improvement. This mortality table (and the probabilities of survival) is available in our website in the “other calculators and tools” section. It should be noted that this table represents mortality experience of individuals who purchased annuities and as such is more conservative (longer life expectancy) than general population mortality. The probabilities of survival to age 97 for both males and females were not available from the tool on our website and have been estimated by me.
One of the big differences between Mr. Kitces calculations and mine has to do with the amount of money spent by the hypothetical retiree from his accumulated savings during the eight year deferral period. Mr. Kitces assumes the retiree will spend $750 per month in the first year of deferral and $922 in the seventh year ($750 increased with 7 years of inflation at 3% per year), whereas I have assumed that the retiree does not want to have a big jump in spendable income in year 8 and will spend the same real dollar amount of $1,672 the retiree expects to receive at age 70 during each year of the deferral ($1,320 per month in the first year and $1,624 per month in the 7th year). The cost of deferrals (the present value of withdrawals from savings) under Mr. Kitces methodology is $65,258 while under my methodology, it is $114,853. This is why deferring commencement looks so much more favorable in Mr. Kitces article (if you spend less today, you can spend more later all things being equal). Of course, it would look even more favorable if the hypothetical retiree decided not to withdraw any amounts during the deferral period.
As I told Leon, I’m not going to make a recommendation one way or another on whether retirees should defer commencement of Social Security. It is an individual decision that involves many factors. If you are willing to defer and don’t spend too much of your accumulated savings during the bridge period, you can generally increase your spendable income in your later years.
Tuesday, September 22, 2015
Retirement Planning in an Uncertain World--Part 2
This is a follow-up to our post of August 11, 2013. In that post, I included what I considered to be one of the most helpful (and most succinct) pieces of advice I have ever read regarding managing the risks involved in financial planning for retirement in today’s world. In his MoneyWatch article of August 7, 2013, my friend and fellow actuary, Steve Vernon said,
"Step 1: Plan to support the life you want, using your best estimate of the future regarding the economy, capital markets, your life expectancy and so on.
Step 2: Be prepared in the event that your forecasts are wrong."
While the simple spending budget calculation spreadsheets (Excluding Social Security and Social Security Bridge) included in this website include a Runout tab (and an inflation adjusted Runout tab) that shows future year’s expected results based on exact realization of all the input assumptions, no changes in assumptions and spending each year exactly equal to the total spendable amount, retirees who use these spreadsheets should have absolutely no expectation that these projected future year’s results will actually occur. They are primarily provided to show the user that the math works, and that under these totally unrealistic conditions, the amount left to heirs at the end of the expected payout period will equal the amount the user inputted on the input page.
The fact that the future numbers in the Runout tabs will be wrong, however, does not invalidate the approach recommended in this website to determine a retiree’s spending budget. The Actuarial Approach anticipates that a retiree’s assets and liabilities will be re-measured at least once a year to adjust the retiree’s budget for differences between actual and assumed experience, for differences between actual and assumed spending and for changes in assumptions. This re-measurement process is essential for keeping the retiree on track. I view this as part of Step 2 in the process Steve Vernon outlined above.
There are lots of possible reasons why forecasts made today will be wrong (deviate from expected results) in the future. These reasons include:
Depending on the proportion of a retiree’s spending budget that is derived from accumulated savings invested in risky assets, differences between actual and assumed investment returns can have a significant effect on the retiree’s spending budget. In order to give retiree’s a sense of how such deviations from the assumed investment return can affect accumulated savings and spending budgets, we have added a new tab to the “Excluding Social Security” spreadsheet (now called “Excluding Social Security V 3.0”). The new tab is called “5-year forecast” and the only difference between the results shown in this tab and the results shown in the Runout tab are attributable to different investment returns inputted by the user for years 1-5 at the top of this tab. If the same assumed investment return is input for each of the 5 years as is input for the assumed investment return in the input tab, the results shown in the 5-year projection will be the same as those shown in the Runout tab. We have also provided two graphs which highlight the differences in beginning of year account balances and total spendable amounts (excluding Social Security and other inflation indexed annuities) resulting from investment experience different from assumed. No smoothing algorithm was applied to the results in the 5-year projection.
We encourage you play with the “actual” investment inputs in the 5-year projection to provide yourself a better sense of the investment risk you are assuming with your current investment strategy (or strategies). As discussed in recent posts, if you have separate budgets for essential expenses, non-essential expenses, emergency expenses, etc. and different investment strategies for these different categories of expenses, you can “kick the tires” on these separate investment strategies to see if you are comfortable with the risk you are assuming for each expense category.
Inspiration for this post and the resulting modification of the “Excluding Social Security” spreadsheet came from discussions with John D. Craig and from work by the Pension Committee of the Actuarial Standards Board on exposure drafts of a standard of actuarial practice regarding assessment and measurement of risk associated with measuring pension obligations. Thanks to both John and the ASB Pension Committee. Readers who are interested in John’s thoughts on Retirement Planning may find this website to be of interest.
"Step 1: Plan to support the life you want, using your best estimate of the future regarding the economy, capital markets, your life expectancy and so on.
Step 2: Be prepared in the event that your forecasts are wrong."
While the simple spending budget calculation spreadsheets (Excluding Social Security and Social Security Bridge) included in this website include a Runout tab (and an inflation adjusted Runout tab) that shows future year’s expected results based on exact realization of all the input assumptions, no changes in assumptions and spending each year exactly equal to the total spendable amount, retirees who use these spreadsheets should have absolutely no expectation that these projected future year’s results will actually occur. They are primarily provided to show the user that the math works, and that under these totally unrealistic conditions, the amount left to heirs at the end of the expected payout period will equal the amount the user inputted on the input page.
The fact that the future numbers in the Runout tabs will be wrong, however, does not invalidate the approach recommended in this website to determine a retiree’s spending budget. The Actuarial Approach anticipates that a retiree’s assets and liabilities will be re-measured at least once a year to adjust the retiree’s budget for differences between actual and assumed experience, for differences between actual and assumed spending and for changes in assumptions. This re-measurement process is essential for keeping the retiree on track. I view this as part of Step 2 in the process Steve Vernon outlined above.
There are lots of possible reasons why forecasts made today will be wrong (deviate from expected results) in the future. These reasons include:
- Differences between actual and assumed investment returns
- Changes in assumed future investment returns
- Differences in actual or assumed spending
- Differences in desired amounts to be left to heirs
- Differences in actual or assumed rates of inflation/desired increases in budgets to keep up with inflation
- Differences in actual or assumed longevity
- Differences in sources of income
Depending on the proportion of a retiree’s spending budget that is derived from accumulated savings invested in risky assets, differences between actual and assumed investment returns can have a significant effect on the retiree’s spending budget. In order to give retiree’s a sense of how such deviations from the assumed investment return can affect accumulated savings and spending budgets, we have added a new tab to the “Excluding Social Security” spreadsheet (now called “Excluding Social Security V 3.0”). The new tab is called “5-year forecast” and the only difference between the results shown in this tab and the results shown in the Runout tab are attributable to different investment returns inputted by the user for years 1-5 at the top of this tab. If the same assumed investment return is input for each of the 5 years as is input for the assumed investment return in the input tab, the results shown in the 5-year projection will be the same as those shown in the Runout tab. We have also provided two graphs which highlight the differences in beginning of year account balances and total spendable amounts (excluding Social Security and other inflation indexed annuities) resulting from investment experience different from assumed. No smoothing algorithm was applied to the results in the 5-year projection.
We encourage you play with the “actual” investment inputs in the 5-year projection to provide yourself a better sense of the investment risk you are assuming with your current investment strategy (or strategies). As discussed in recent posts, if you have separate budgets for essential expenses, non-essential expenses, emergency expenses, etc. and different investment strategies for these different categories of expenses, you can “kick the tires” on these separate investment strategies to see if you are comfortable with the risk you are assuming for each expense category.
Inspiration for this post and the resulting modification of the “Excluding Social Security” spreadsheet came from discussions with John D. Craig and from work by the Pension Committee of the Actuarial Standards Board on exposure drafts of a standard of actuarial practice regarding assessment and measurement of risk associated with measuring pension obligations. Thanks to both John and the ASB Pension Committee. Readers who are interested in John’s thoughts on Retirement Planning may find this website to be of interest.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)